Pricing

UCSD MGT 100 Week 07

Kenneth C. Wilbur and Dan Yavorsky

Let’s reflect

How firms set prices

  • Importance and challenge
  • Common approaches
  • Economic Value to the Customer
  • Human factors
  • Using Demand Model to Price

Pricing importance

  • Average US net margin is 8% (Damodaran Online)

  • Widely cited research by McKinsey

    - 1% price increase can lead to 11% profit increase 
    - 1% price decrease can lead to 8% profit decrease
    - Logic assumes no decrease in quantity
    - Correlations, but widely misinterpreted as causal
  • Consultants say most companies price too low;
    price is low-hanging fruit

Price changes are risky & scary

How firms set prices

Limited-data analyses

  • EVC / Value pricing
  • Competitor price benchmarking
  • Cost-based pricing

Stated-Preference Data

  • Open-ended: How much are you wtp? $___
  • Prompted: Would you buy (product) at ($price)?
  • Conjoint Analysis: Designs can be incentivized or not

Revealed-Preference Data

  • Simulated purchase environments, Test markets

  • Algorithms (bandits, rev mgmt), Experiments (Amazon pricing labs)

  • Demand estimation

    - Requires data, exogneous price variation, human attention/expertise 

Customer co-determination

  • Monopsony, auctions, negotiation, pay-what-you-want

None

  • Seller takes market price

Value Pricing: Price in (cost, wtp)

  • But… how do you learn wtp? Esp. if you have not sold before?

    • For large time/budget: Conjoint, simulated purchase environments, test markets, …
    • For small time/budget: Economic Value to the Customer (EVC)
  • EVC: estimates customer benefit from a product, relative to the next best alternative

  • EVC & VP are often used by new firms, highly differentiated products & when no credible market research

  • Steps: 1. Calculate EVC, 2. Choose a price in (Cost, EVC)

How to calculate EVC(x\(\vert\)y)

  1. Select the best available alternative y and find its price

    - Interview target customers to learn how they solve the core need (y)
    - If wrong y, EVC estimate will be too high
  2. Determine non-price costs of using y and x

    - Include start-up costs and/or post-purchase costs
    - Make sure NonPriceCosts(x) exclude the price of x (why?)
  3. Determine the incremental economic value of x over y

    - Usually, functional benefits or non-price cost decreases    
  4. EVC = Price(y) + ( NonPriceCosts(y) - NonPriceCosts(x) ) + IncrementalValue(x\(\vert\)y)

    - In practice, 99% of effort is getting the assumptions right 

EVC tips

  • Remember: y might not be a commercial product.

  • EVC and y often vary across customer segments

    - Calculate heterogeneous EVC(x|y) for multiple y
  • Unquantifiable factors influence price selection in (cost,EVC)

  • If EVC(x\(\vert\)y)<0, reconsider product or target customer

Example: What is EVC(Batteriser\(\vert\)y)?

  • The Batteriser is a durable metal sleeve that increases disposable battery life by 800%. With a thickness of just 0.1 millimetres, the sleeve can be fitted over any size battery, in any size compartment

  • Assume the typical battery costs $0.50

“Pricing Thermometer’’

  • How much inducement do you give your customer?

  • How will customers, competitors, suppliers react?

    - SR vs. LR? More judgment than math. "Your margin is my opportunity"

Choosing p in (cost, EVC)

  • Some advise: \(Price = Cost + (EVC - Cost)*{z%}\)

     - I've heard z = 25%, 33%, 50%, and 70%
     - Do you want profits or growth? What's your exit?
  • Human factors to consider when making your judgment:

    - Perceived benefit - actual benefit
    - Perceived costs - actual costs
    - Consumer price sensitivity, reference price of y 
    - Established pricing benchmarks
    - Fairness, signaling 
    - Customer risk of adoption, skepticism; brand credibility

Conjoint works for pricing too

Van Westendorp Pricing Model

  • Goal: Estimate stated WTP range for each customer

  • Survey target customers: At what price is (product)…

      - Too Cheap? I.e., that you would question its quality
      - Good Value?
      - Expensive?
      - Too Expensive? I.e., that you would not consider buying 
  • Plot CDFs

      - Too Cheap and Good Value decrease with price
      - Expensive and Too Expensive increase with price
      - Look for crossing points

  • “Too cheap” meets “Expensive”: “Point of Marginal Cheapness”

        - VW says: Don't price below PMC
  • “Good Value” meets “Too Expensive”: “Point of Marginal Expensiveness”

        - VW says: Don't price above PME
  • “Too Cheap” meets “Too Expensive”: Min. # of price-refusers

  • “Good Value” meets “Expensive”: Possibly max. # of price-accepters

  • Strengths

        - Estimable with survey data only; Estimates distributions of consumer heterogeneity; Incorporates reference prices and price-quality signals
        - Extensible to incorporate stated purchase intentions at each price. Add cost data, you can then max. profits
  • Limitations

        - Identifies a price range, not a price
        - Thinking about 4 CDFs is difficult, easy to misinterpret
        - Stated-preference data only; disregards competitors & marginal costs, hence don't use standalone
        - Limited field evidence that it works well

Signals and Perceived Quality

  • Signals of high quality

    - High prices, Brand names, Warranties, Return policies, Ad spending
    - Costly signals when the firm doesn't deliver
    - Brand reputation can convey credibility
  • Signals of low quality

    - Low prices, Price promotions, Price-matching guarantees
    - Signals that look too good to be true
    - "If it's so good, why is it so cheap?''
  • Prescription: Price consistent with your quality position in the market

    - Otherwise, you undercut your own message and leave money on the table
    - Findings replicate in numerous contexts 

Human factors: Price as a signal

Human factors: Non-monetary costs

  • Total customer cost is

    Cognitive cost to decide the purchase 
    + Physical cost to acquire the product 
    + Financial payment
  • Simplicity can increase sales. Remove frictions

Human factors: Perceived prices

  • Which is the better bargain?

    • Regular price $0.89, sale price $0.75
    • Regular price $0.93, sale price $0.79

Left-digit bias: Demand Effects

Left-digit bias: Lyft rides

Human factors: Anchoring

  • “You are lying on the beach on a hot lazy afternoon. For about an hour now, you have been thinking about an ice-cold bottle of your favorite beer. One of your friends gets up to make a phone call and offers to get you your favorite beer from a small run-down grocery store on the way back. Your friend says that the beer might be expensive and asks the maximum price that you are willing to pay. If the price is higher, your friend won’t buy the beer. What is your maximum price?
  • fancy resort hotel

Human factors: Price salience

  • Show the price early, late or never?

    - Drinks in a loud nightclub
    - USPS "Forever Stamps"
    - Price advertising, coupons
  • Price salience emphasizes Savings or Exclusivity

Human factors: Decoy effects

  • Choose 1:

    • Brand A: Rated 50/100, priced at 1.80
    • Brand B: Rated 70/100, priced at 2.60
  • 33% chose A

Human factors: Decoy effects

  • Choose 1:

    • Brand A: Rated 40/100, priced at 1.60
    • Brand B: Rated 50/100, priced at 1.80
    • Brand C: Rated 70/100, priced at 2.60
  • 47% chose B (why?)

Field evidence in Diamonds

4 vertical attributes

Decoy Effect Research

  • Context: Online diamond sales

        - #1 online diamond retailer, 50% share, big US brand 
        - Retailer used a drop shipping model and fixed 18-20% markup
        - Anonymous diamond suppliers create listings, set prices
        - Diamonds listed individually; listings disappear upon purchase
        - Consumers filter by attributes and price
        - Retailer orders filtered listings by ascending price
        - Great setting: Rare-purchase category, high-price, limited/no fit attributes, many unknowledgeable consumers 
  • Wu & Cosguner

        - Scraped 7 months of 2.7 million daily diamond listings 
        - Decoy-dominant relationships were frequent
        - Used a proportional hazards model to estimate decoy/dominant effect on time-to-sale

Dominant-Dominated Diamond Pair

  • Dominant/decoy pair defined as either:
    1. Same attributes, different price
    2. Dominated attributes, disordered price
    • In both cases, dominant is more attractive, decoy is less attractive
  • Example:
    • Dominant: 1-carat, Excellent cut, D color, VVS1 clarity, $3000 price
    • Decoy: 1-carat, Very Good cut, D color, VVS1 clarity, $3500 price
  • Search result listings made decoy/dominant pair detection difficult, so detection depended on frequency of dominant/decoy listings

Findings

  • 11%-25% likelihood of Dominant/decoy relationship detection
  • Dominant diamonds sold 1.8-3.2x faster upon decoy detections
  • Simulations predict Decoy Effect increased retailer’s gross profit by 14.3%

Implications

  • Researchers: Decoy pricing is important & evident in the wild

  • Managers: Consider decoy effects when designing product assortments, pricing engine and search engine results algorithm

  • Consumers: Beware dominated products when searching; and evaluate dissimilar products individually

        - Or, buy a lab-grown diamond

Economic factors: Price discrimination

  • Amazon v. B&N

  • Purchase time: Airline, Cruise tickets

  • Needs: e.g. Business vs. Home segments

  • Skimming by delivery time: Movie release windows

  • Geography: Typically accounts for 20% of variation in online prices

  • Quantity: Cups of coffee, Paper towels

  • Reduce resentment via new/loyal customer, merit (veterans, seniors), ability to pay/sliding scale, value provided, cost of supply

  • Always frame price differences as discounts

Economic factors: Beware a price war!

  • If you explicitly mention a competitor’s price

    • You make Customer aware of Competitor
    • Competitor will notice: You invite them to match or retaliate
  • Better to price-compare vs. unnamed/generic competitor

  • Who wins a price war?

    • Only one winner: Customer
    • All firms suffer, some die
    • Most likely to survive: Seller with lowest cost structure
    • Smart firms avoid price wars & keep costs secret

Refresher: Price Elasticity of Demand

  • \(elas.=\frac{d(lnQ)}{d(lnP)}=\frac{P}{Q}\frac{dQ}{dP}\le 0\)

  • For \(-1<elas.<0\), we say demand is price-inelastic

  • For \(elas.<-1\), we say demand is price-elastic

  • Elasticity is “scale-free”

  • We can calculate elasticity at a point, or on an interval

  • Results depend on interval width and demand curvature

  • Narrower intervals yield more precise elasticities

Refresher: Price Elasticity of Demand

  • \(elas.=\frac{d(lnQ)}{d(lnP)}=\frac{P}{Q}\frac{dQ}{dP}\)

  • A special class of demand functions have constant elasticity

    \(Q=e^a*P^b\) for \(a>0\) & \(b>0\), then \(elast.=b\)

    Implies \(ln Q=\alpha+\beta lnP\), called “log-log”

      Have to handle price endogeneity to estimate right beta 
  • C.E. imposes a particular shape on demand & enables easy price optimization, given marginal cost data

  • But, C.E. restricts demand -> can lead to suboptimal pricing

How to use demand model to set price

  • \(q_j(p_j)=N\hat{s}_j(p_j)\)

  • Total contribution = \(\pi(p) = q_j(p_j)[p_j-c_j(q_j(p_j))]\)

  • Grid search:

    • Choose candidate prices \(p_m = p_1, p_2, ..., p_M\)
    • \(p^*=argmax_{p_m} \pi(p_m)\)
    • Optional: Repeat using a more refined grid around \(p^*\)
  • We often assume \(c_j(q_j(p_j))=c\) for convenience

  • Multiproduct line pricing requires sum over brand’s owned products

  • Can you predict competitor price reaction, or how your demand responds to new competitor price? How?

  • T/F: Stated preferences are more reliable than revealed preferences for pricing

Class script

  • Use demand model to trace out a demand curve and optimize price

Wrapping up

Homework

  • Let’s take a look

Recap

  • The most common price setting methods are value pricing, competitor price matching, and cost-based. All 3 are incomplete
  • Consumers generally expect product prices to reflect quality positions in the marketplace
  • Optimal pricing requires attention to both economic factors and human factors

Going further