UCSD MGT 100 Week 07
Average US net margin is 8% (Damodaran Online)
Widely cited research by McKinsey
- 1% price increase can lead to 11% profit increase
- 1% price decrease can lead to 8% profit decrease
- Logic assumes no decrease in quantity
- Correlations, but widely misinterpreted as causal
Consultants say most companies price too low;
price is low-hanging fruit
Simulated purchase environments, Test markets
Algorithms (bandits, rev mgmt), Experiments (Amazon pricing labs)
Demand estimation
- Requires data, exogneous price variation, human attention/expertise
But… how do you learn wtp? Esp. if you have not sold before?
EVC: estimates customer benefit from a product, relative to the next best alternative
EVC & VP are often used by new firms, highly differentiated products & when no credible market research
Steps: 1. Calculate EVC, 2. Choose a price in (Cost, EVC)
Select the best available alternative y and find its price
- Interview target customers to learn how they solve the core need (y)
- If wrong y, EVC estimate will be too high
Determine non-price costs of using y and x
- Include start-up costs and/or post-purchase costs
- Make sure NonPriceCosts(x) exclude the price of x (why?)
Determine the incremental economic value of x over y
- Usually, functional benefits or non-price cost decreases
EVC = Price(y) + ( NonPriceCosts(y) - NonPriceCosts(x) ) + IncrementalValue(x\(\vert\)y)
- In practice, 99% of effort is getting the assumptions right
Remember: y might not be a commercial product.
EVC and y often vary across customer segments
- Calculate heterogeneous EVC(x|y) for multiple y
Unquantifiable factors influence price selection in (cost,EVC)
If EVC(x\(\vert\)y)<0, reconsider product or target customer
The Batteriser is a durable metal sleeve that increases disposable battery life by 800%. With a thickness of just 0.1 millimetres, the sleeve can be fitted over any size battery, in any size compartment
Assume the typical battery costs $0.50
How much inducement do you give your customer?
How will customers, competitors, suppliers react?
- SR vs. LR? More judgment than math. "Your margin is my opportunity"
Some advise: \(Price = Cost + (EVC - Cost)*{z%}\)
- I've heard z = 25%, 33%, 50%, and 70%
- Do you want profits or growth? What's your exit?
Human factors to consider when making your judgment:
- Perceived benefit - actual benefit
- Perceived costs - actual costs
- Consumer price sensitivity, reference price of y
- Established pricing benchmarks
- Fairness, signaling
- Customer risk of adoption, skepticism; brand credibility
Goal: Estimate stated WTP range for each customer
Survey target customers: At what price is (product)…
- Too Cheap? I.e., that you would question its quality
- Good Value?
- Expensive?
- Too Expensive? I.e., that you would not consider buying
Plot CDFs
- Too Cheap and Good Value decrease with price
- Expensive and Too Expensive increase with price
- Look for crossing points
“Too cheap” meets “Expensive”: “Point of Marginal Cheapness”
- VW says: Don't price below PMC
“Good Value” meets “Too Expensive”: “Point of Marginal Expensiveness”
- VW says: Don't price above PME
“Too Cheap” meets “Too Expensive”: Min. # of price-refusers
“Good Value” meets “Expensive”: Possibly max. # of price-accepters
Strengths
- Estimable with survey data only; Estimates distributions of consumer heterogeneity; Incorporates reference prices and price-quality signals
- Extensible to incorporate stated purchase intentions at each price. Add cost data, you can then max. profits
Limitations
- Identifies a price range, not a price
- Thinking about 4 CDFs is difficult, easy to misinterpret
- Stated-preference data only; disregards competitors & marginal costs, hence don't use standalone
- Limited field evidence that it works well
Signals of high quality
- High prices, Brand names, Warranties, Return policies, Ad spending
- Costly signals when the firm doesn't deliver
- Brand reputation can convey credibility
Signals of low quality
- Low prices, Price promotions, Price-matching guarantees
- Signals that look too good to be true
- "If it's so good, why is it so cheap?''
Prescription: Price consistent with your quality position in the market
- Otherwise, you undercut your own message and leave money on the table
- Findings replicate in numerous contexts
Total customer cost is
Cognitive cost to decide the purchase
+ Physical cost to acquire the product
+ Financial payment
Simplicity can increase sales. Remove frictions
Which is the better bargain?
Show the price early, late or never?
- Drinks in a loud nightclub
- USPS "Forever Stamps"
- Price advertising, coupons
Price salience emphasizes Savings or Exclusivity
Choose 1:
33% chose A
Choose 1:
47% chose B (why?)
Context: Online diamond sales
- #1 online diamond retailer, 50% share, big US brand
- Retailer used a drop shipping model and fixed 18-20% markup
- Anonymous diamond suppliers create listings, set prices
- Diamonds listed individually; listings disappear upon purchase
- Consumers filter by attributes and price
- Retailer orders filtered listings by ascending price
- Great setting: Rare-purchase category, high-price, limited/no fit attributes, many unknowledgeable consumers
Wu & Cosguner
- Scraped 7 months of 2.7 million daily diamond listings
- Decoy-dominant relationships were frequent
- Used a proportional hazards model to estimate decoy/dominant effect on time-to-sale
Researchers: Decoy pricing is important & evident in the wild
Managers: Consider decoy effects when designing product assortments, pricing engine and search engine results algorithm
Consumers: Beware dominated products when searching; and evaluate dissimilar products individually
- Or, buy a lab-grown diamond
Amazon v. B&N
Purchase time: Airline, Cruise tickets
Needs: e.g. Business vs. Home segments
Skimming by delivery time: Movie release windows
Geography: Typically accounts for 20% of variation in online prices
Quantity: Cups of coffee, Paper towels
Reduce resentment via new/loyal customer, merit (veterans, seniors), ability to pay/sliding scale, value provided, cost of supply
Always frame price differences as discounts
If you explicitly mention a competitor’s price
Better to price-compare vs. unnamed/generic competitor
Who wins a price war?
\(elas.=\frac{d(lnQ)}{d(lnP)}=\frac{P}{Q}\frac{dQ}{dP}\le 0\)
For \(-1<elas.<0\), we say demand is price-inelastic
For \(elas.<-1\), we say demand is price-elastic
Elasticity is “scale-free”
We can calculate elasticity at a point, or on an interval
Results depend on interval width and demand curvature
Narrower intervals yield more precise elasticities
\(elas.=\frac{d(lnQ)}{d(lnP)}=\frac{P}{Q}\frac{dQ}{dP}\)
A special class of demand functions have constant elasticity
\(Q=e^a*P^b\) for \(a>0\) & \(b>0\), then \(elast.=b\)
Implies \(ln Q=\alpha+\beta lnP\), called “log-log”
Have to handle price endogeneity to estimate right beta
C.E. imposes a particular shape on demand & enables easy price optimization, given marginal cost data
But, C.E. restricts demand -> can lead to suboptimal pricing
\(q_j(p_j)=N\hat{s}_j(p_j)\)
Total contribution = \(\pi(p) = q_j(p_j)[p_j-c_j(q_j(p_j))]\)
Grid search:
We often assume \(c_j(q_j(p_j))=c\) for convenience
Multiproduct line pricing requires sum over brand’s owned products
Can you predict competitor price reaction, or how your demand responds to new competitor price? How?
Dynamic Online Pricing with Incomplete Information Using Multiarmed Bandit Experiments
Universal Paperclips : Fun free price setting game